ECONOMIC PERSPECTIVE TO EFFICIENT SOIL FERTILITY MANAGEMENT IN NEPAL
INTRODUCTION:
Soil is the uppermost part of the earth’s crust formed by the
weathering of rocks and containing humus and material transfer. It is the very
crucial and precious natural resource, and a non-renewable one in short term.
Soils vary in terms of origin, appearance, characteristics and production
capacity. The well-developed soils have a distinct profile with different layers.
Major types of soils are formed from rocks by weathering processes over long
periods extending to more than 1000 years. During weathering, physical
disintegration of rocks and minerals occurs, further chemical and biochemical
soil forming processes lead to their decomposition. Soils vary largely with
respect to their natural fertility and productivity resulting in plant growth
ranging from practically zero growth on extreme problem soils to abundant
luxuriant growth of natural vegetation. Soil fertility is the inherent capacity
of soil that enables it to provide essential plant elements in quantities and
proportions for the growth of specified plant when other factors are favorable
(Panda, 2010). Soil fertility evaluation is the measurement of availability of
macronutrients like Nitrogen, Phosphorus, Potassium, Calcium, Sulphur and
micronutrients for the growth and development of plant.
Properties
of soil
Physical
property
The texture, structure, color are
important physical properties of soil. Healthy soils have high aggregate
stability, low bulk density, and high available water capacity.
Chemical
property
Similarly, pH, organic matter, macro
and micronutrients are important chemical properties determining crop
production and productivity. Fertile soils have neutral to slightly acidic pH,
abundant and stable levels of phosphorus and potassium, adequate levels of
micronutrients, and low salinity.
Biological
property
Fertile and productive soils have
large amounts of organic matter, high levels of active carbon, adequate and
stable levels of mineralizable nitrogen (having too-high levels of nitrates can
decrease soil health), and a thriving microbial ecosystem.
In the world only a
small proportion of soil has good level of fertility. Most soils have medium fertility
and some have even lower fertility, and are often referred to as marginal
soils. The fertile soils are deep alluvial soils formed from river basins,
organic matter-rich soils on loess material, nutrient rich Vertisols and
volcanic soils. In most countries with large food demand, cropping cannot be
restricted to the natural fertility of soil because of the large population and
general shortage of arable land inorganic fertilizers are applied as external
inputs to increase the productivity. The fertility of poor soil can be improved
considerably using several methods and has been demonstrated in many countries.
Degraded soils can also be restored to a satisfactory fertility level if
managed properly. While, under poor management condition the highly fertile
soil can be seriously depleted to the extent that the soils may become useless
for agricultural production.
IMPORTANCE
OF SOIL FERTILITY:
The Nepalese economy
relies heavily upon the agriculture sector, a source of livelihoods for 65.6%
of the country’s active population and contributes 28.89% to the total gross
domestic product (Agriculture diary, 2075). The rapid population growth rate at
1.35% per year has placed considerable pressure on Nepal’s natural resources to
meet the food demands of its population and has raised concerns over the
long-term sustainability of its agriculture (Agriculture diary, 2075). Soil fertility is one of the key factors in
determining agricultural production. Healthy soil produces healthy and
vigorous plants which help to increase crop production and can address the
problem of food insecurity. Improved soil fertility and nutrient management
system is essential for successful cropping. Soil is the foundation on which
all input-based high-production systems can be built. Fertile and healthy soil
increase plant growth, reduce erosion, prevent against pest and disease
outbreak, and can serve as a carbon sink.
STATUS
OF SOIL FERTILITY IN NEPAL:
The
soils of Nepal are derived mainly from young parent material and are highly
variable based on the topography. A Land Resource Mapping Project (LRMP)
carried countrywide survey and produced a soil classification report based on
USDA soil taxonomy in 1986. It reported that 4 soil orders covering 14 soils
group are encountered in Nepal. The main order of soil found in Nepal are
Entisols, Inceptisols, Mollisols and Alfisols. However, Spodosols, Histosols,
Ultisols and Aridosols are occasionally found.
Mandal (2007) reported that 60% soils of
Nepal have low organic matter (OM), 23% have low phosphorus (P), 18% have low
potassium (K), and 67% of the soils are acidic. MOAD (2017) estimated that 310
kg/ha of plant nutrient is lost annually because of the cereal-based farming
system, whereas only 67 kg/ha of fertilizer is added to the soil through
various fertilizer sources. However, the poor soil management practice in
cultivated lands has led to a higher rate of soil erosion, decreased crop
production and productivity, and declined soil quality (Pimentel, 2013). The
data on soil science results indicate that majority of Nepalese soil are low to
medium in major nutrients, very low in organic matter and half of the soils are
acidic in nature (Jaishy & Mandal 1999). In producing most of crop that
remove in an average 14 kg Ca and 11 kg Mg per hectare per crop (Tripathi
1999).
CONSTRAINTS
ASSOCIATED WITH SOIL FERTILITY:
Major
problems associated with soil fertility management in Nepal are deforestation,
which gives way for enhanced erosion by water and wind, salinization, flooding,
water logging, and fertility depletion (Hartemink, et al. 2008). It is
estimated that to form one inch of fertile soil, it takes about 500- 1000
years, but the same can be destroyed even in a short and single rain event.
Rowell (1994) reported that various studies have estimated the soil loss
ranging from 0.2 - 10.5%. Soil is primary resource for the households in
agrarian country so, management of its fertility is essential to ensure the
prosperity of such households. Continuous cultivation without addition of
substantial amounts of soil organic matter in terai region and sharp decrease
in soil organic carbon and nitrogen (Shrestha et al., 2004), increased cropping
intensity, use of high yielding varieties, and increasing irrigation facilities
have rapidly exhausted nutrients from soil. There is no doubt that demands on
the soil resources will continue to increase and that further
intensification of agriculture will be
needed to meet
food demands in the
future (Schreier et al. 1995, Pandey et al. 1996). Substantial use of
farmyard manures (FYM), compost, crop residue, and fertilizers has increased
lately to overcome the need of micro and major elements. The chemical
fertilizers containing Nitrogen and Phosphorus applied in the field is washed
away during rainfall due to runoff and mixes in the water bodies, this
increases the nutrient content of water bodies resulting the condition called
eutrophication. In eutrophication there is rapid growth of aquatic plant bodies
resulting in the deficiency of oxygen in the water bodies (Hypoxia). Due to the
depletion of oxygen in the water bodies the aquatic animals are adversely
affected. The nutrient pollution is characterized as the marginal external cost
which is the vertical gap between the narrowly defined marginal production cost
and the more inclusive marginal social cost. These costs increase with
increases in demand for the commodity, and as production increases, the
downstream effect of hypoxia increases the gap between the production costs and
the social costs. Internalizing some of the social costs involve producer level
decisions on alternate farm management practices. This report aims to
investigate the existing externalities in the soil fertility management process
and also identify the possible solutions to internalize such externalities.
ECONOMIC
EXPLANATION:
The soil fertility has
important positive and negative external effects.
NEGATIVE EXTERNALITY:
Increased application of
Phosphorus, Nitrogen and Potassium, forms the core strategy to increase soil
fertility and improve agricultural productivity in response to societal
demands. The prevailing farming practices involve socially suboptimal levels of
use and containment that causes nutrient runoff into streams, rivers and
ultimately to the sea. Such nutrient enrichment of water bodies
(eutrophication) enhance the growth conditions for aquatic plant-life thereby
increasing biological oxygen demand for species competing for resources. This
leads to negative externalities in downstream of the agricultural region, in
the form of water pollution reduced fish and other populations of economic
interest, and lower recreational values. The economic approaches to internalize
such externality are standards, taxes, and subsidies. According to Kaldor’s welfare criterion: “if a certain change in
economic organization or policy makes some people better off and others worse
off, then a change will increase social welfare if those who gain from the
change could compensate the losers and still be better off than before. Thus,
if any policy change benefits any one section of the society (gainers) to such
an extent that it is better off even after the payment of compensation to the
other sections of the society (losers) out of the benefits received, then that
change leads to increase in social welfare”. Informal flow of a
Kaldor-Hicks type of compensation is assumed as long as the benefits from the
first outweigh the losses of the second, consumer surpluses are expected. The
problem occurs when the system overloads and downstream losses exceed the
benefits of intensive agriculture.
Pigouvian Tax
A
Pigouvian tax is a tax on any market activity that generates negative
externalities. The pigouvian tax is intended to correct an undesirable or
inefficient market outcome. It does so by being set equal to the social cost of
the negative externalities. In the presence of negative externalities, the
social cost of a market activity is not covered by the private cost of the
activity. In such a case, the market outcome is not efficient and may lead to
overconsumption of the product causing market failure. “The negative
externality of the nutrient pollution is characterized as the marginal external
cost which is the vertical gap between the narrowly defined marginal production
cost and the more inclusive marginal social cost. These costs increase with
increases in demand for the commodity, and as production increases the
downstream effect of hypoxia increases the gap between the production costs and
the social costs”. Internalizing some of the social costs involve producer
level decisions on alternate farm management practices. The remedy recommended
in mainstream economics in this situation is some form of Pigouvian Tax which
is set to the marginal external cost. A tax shifts the marginal external cost
curve up by the amount of the externality. If the tax is placed on the quantity
of runoff from the field, the farmers have an incentive to reduce production to
the socially optimum level. If the tax is placed on the percentage of runoff
per unit of production, the farmer has incentive to change production processes
or technology.
POSITIVE EXTERNALITY:
The fertile and healthy
soils increase biodiversity, prevent erosion, sequester carbon, and reduce pest
and disease outbreaks, they provide public benefits not captured by a single
farmer. In economics, we refer to such benefits as positive externalities.
These benefits are unpriced leading to market failure. The major approaches of
internalizing positive externalities are:
Pigouvian subsidies:
Pigouvian subsidies is
the most straightforward way for societies to internalize positive
externalities. This method of internalizing externality is named after Arthur
Pigou, an English economist who developed much of the theory around market
externalities. A Pigouvian tax would reflect the public cost of an action that
is not otherwise internalized in market transactions. Conversely, a Pigouvian
subsidy would compensate a private agent for public benefits provided by some
behavior. In the case of soil fertility, a Pigouvian subsidy would entail the
government paying farmers to engage in soil fertility management practices.
However, this is not an easy task. According to the theory, the size of the
Pigouvian subsidy should be equal to only the benefits not captured by the
private user. This number is difficult or impossible to estimate in the case of
soil fertility. In practice, a Pigouvian subsidy that is too large will cost
society more money than is needed to achieve the desired level of soil
fertility.
Quota-based policies (cap-and-trade):
Another way to
internalize externalities is cap-and-trade system. This approach is more
suitable to manage negative externalities, and is probably not the most
appropriate for soil fertility. However, carbon cap-and-trade programs
affecting land use management as farmers are being compensated for practices
that sequester carbon.
Coase theorem inspired bargaining:
The Coase theorem
suggests that private bargaining can internalize externalities if property
rights are well-defined and transaction costs are low. In the case of soil
fertility, transaction costs are certainly not low, so, the Pigouvian subsidy
would be a more realistic and effective approach for internalizing the
externality.
RECOMMENDATION:
Soil fertility is a very
customizable feature of soil. Since its management is directly related to crop
production levels, both long and short term fertility management practices are
necessary in order to either maintain existing good health of soil or to
restore the fertility, so that sustainable crop production could be achieved.
Moreover, soil fertility is inextricably linked to environmental resilience,
and ecosystem services. However, while maintaining soil fertility there is a
presence of both negative and positive externalities which must be taken into
account in every planning and decision making process. The negative externality
mostly occurs due to the runoff of nutrients from soil that increases the
nutrient content of water bodies resulting a condition called eutrophication.
It is hard to precisely quantify the costs bore by ecosystem due to these
externalities, while the solutions to these might be as wide as reformation and
revision of economic and policy frameworks. The solutions to the negative
externality includes the Pigouvian tax through which the individuals degrading
water quality while maintaining soil fertility are also made accountable, and
thus compensate the affected. However, there are positive externalities
associated with soil fertility also. As fertile soil maintains the balance in
ecosystem and helps in conservation of ecosystem and biodiversity, this
externality can be internalized by Pigouvian subsidy and carbon cap-and-trade
method. In case of Negative externality, Pigouvian tax is the best method of
internalization of externality while if positive externality is realized,
Pigouvian subsidy would be more realistic in case of soil fertility management.
CONCLUSION:
There are several ways
to manage soil fertility rather than merely depending upon chemical sources.
Educating farmers on reducing pollution from agricultural activities, along
with assisting them with choosing right amounts of nutrient and pesticide usage
can play a vital role. Education of polluters is probably the best method the
public has for reducing non –point source pollution problems. Similarly, use of
bio-fertilizers and addition of organic materials are potential can be an alternatives
to chemical fertilizers since it helps to minimize eutrophication. While from
economic perspective, the negative externalities caused by the addition of
chemical fertilizers while maintaining soil fertility can be solved by levying
pigouvian tax to the polluter and the affected individuals should get
compensation. Similarly, there is positive externality of soil fertility, as
fertile soil maintains the balance in ecosystem and helps in conservation of
ecosystem and biodiversity, this externality can be internalized by Pigouvian
subsidy and carbon cap-and-trade method.
REFERENCES:
Agriculture
Diary.2075. Agriculture Information & Communication Center, Ministry of
Agricultural Development, Government of Nepal, Harihar Bhawan, Lalitpur.
Hartemink, A.E., McBratney, A., Minasny, B.,
2008. Trends in soil science education: Looking beyond the number of students. J.
Soil Water Conserv. 63, 76–83.
Jaishy,
S.N. and S.N. Mandal.1999. Soil fertility management extension activities
Nepal, Paper presented in the workshop "Enhanced farming livelihood in
the mid-hills of Nepal through improved soil fertility management"
Organized by Soil Science Division of NARC and University of reading UK. 25-26
July 1999, Kathmandu, Nepal.
Mandal, S.N. 2007.National Workshop on
Sustainable Soil Management Program; Soil Management Directorate: Lalitpur,
Nepal.
MoAD.
2017. Statistical Information on Nepalese Agriculture. Kathmandu: Ministry of
Agriculture Development.
Panda SC. 2010.Soil Management and Organic Farming. India:
Agrobios, Bharat Printing Press; 462 p.
Pandey SP., 1996. Soil fertility and nutrient management. In: Sustainable
management of soils in rainfed cropping systems in the mid-hills of Nepal,
Compilation of Main Findings. Swiss Development Cooperation (SDC)/Nepal,
Agricultural Project Services Centre (APROSC), Kathmandu, Nepal.
Pimentel, D., Burgess, M.2013. Soil Erosion
Threatens Food Production. Agriculture. (3): 443–463. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Rowell, D.L. 1994. Soil Science: Methods and
Applications. Prentice Hall, Harlow.
Schreier H, PB Shah, and S Brown. 1995. Challenges in mountain
resource management in Nepal: Process, trends and dynamics in a middle mountain
watershed. Workshop Proceedings. International Development Research Center and
International Center for Integrated Mountain Development, Kathmandu, Nepal
Shrestha, B.M., Sitaula, B.K., Singh, B.R. and Bajracharya, R.M.
2004. Soil Organic Carbon Stocks in Soil Aggregates Under Different Land Use
Systems in Nepal. Agro-ecosystems, 70(2): 201-213.
Tripathi, B.P.1999. Review on acid soil and its management in
Nepal. Lumle Seminar Paper No. 99/1, Lumle Agric. Research Center, Kaski,
Nepal, 11 pages.
Comments
Post a Comment